≡ Menu

Some Links

David Henderson writes in the Wall Street Journal about the 2025 winners of the Nobel Prize in economics. Two slices:

The most important issue in economics is growth. That’s why Monday’s announcement of three winners of the 2025 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences is heartening. The Nobel committee awarded it to three economists “for having explained innovation-driven economic growth.” The winners are Dutch-born American-Israeli Joel Mokyr of Northwestern University and Tel Aviv University, Frenchman Philippe Aghion of the Collège de France, Insead in Paris and the London School of Economics and Political Science, and Canadian Peter Howitt of Brown University. Mr. Mokyr won half of the approximately $1.16 million award, while Messrs. Aghion and Howitt will share the other half.

Mr. Mokyr is an economic historian who has focused on understanding why we got the so-called hockey stick of human prosperity, a metaphor in which the long, flat shaft represents centuries of economic stagnation before the Industrial Revolution and the short, sharp blade represents sustained growth in gross domestic product and in GDP per capita in the U.S. and much of Europe after the revolution. Messrs. Aghion and Howitt have focused on theoretical modeling of economic growth, enabling us to understand how various factors interact to bring about growth. Their work complements Mr. Mokyr’s.

…..

Each year, I wait with trepidation to see who has won the Nobel Prize in economics. Many economists seem to want the prize to be given for complex models that don’t matter much. When I saw who won it on Monday, I was happy. Economic growth is the reason extreme poverty has become much rarer around the world, life expectancy has increased dramatically, and most Americans now own many things that were unobtainable luxuries decades ago. All three winners recognized that because economic growth is crucial, we need to understand how we got it and how we can keep it.

Also writing about this year’s economics Nobelists is Reason‘s Billy Binion. A slice:

Together, the trio had explained how innovation drives economic growth, the academy said, when economic stagnation had been the rule, as opposed to the exception, for the vast majority of human history. As a result of that upswing, countless people have been lifted out of poverty.

For his part, Mokyr’s work has focused on the intersection of economics, culture, and history, emphasizing both the importance of understanding why various technologies work if they are to successfully build on each other, as well the affluence that comes from openness to new ideas. In reviewing Mokyr’s 2016 book, A Culture of Growth: The Origins of the Modern Economy, the classical liberal economist Deirdre McCloskey wrote that Mokyr “is a Nobel-worthy economic scientist, right down to his wingtip shoes.

GMU Econ alum Jeremy Horpedahl responds to an uninformed tweet about Joel Mokyr and China: (HT Scott Lincicome)

Mokyr literally has a 500-page book titled Two Paths to Prosperity: Culture and Institutions in Europe and China coming out next month. His first “big ideas” book, The Lever of Riches, has a full chapter exploring why China didn’t have an Industrial Revolution like Europe. He continued to investigate this question throughout his career, such as Part V of his 2018 book A Culture of Growth.

And here are links to the many “Quotations of the Day” from Joel Mokyr that have been featured at Cafe Hayek.

Robert Whaples reviews Andrew Leigh’s The Shortest History of Economics. Two slices:

As Leigh explains in the introduction, the “secret of our discipline is that the most powerful insights come from a handful of big ideas that anyone can comprehend” (5). Three of these are straight out of Intro to Econ and/or Adam Smith: incentives really matter; specialization leads to big productivity gains; and as specialization flourishes, trade becomes invaluable. The fourth is that the “big events are rarely driven by sudden shifts in norms or culture” (7) but more often by new technologies or changing policies. A couple of notable economic historians would dispute this. In A Culture of Growth, for example, Joel Mokyr argues that the primary driver of the Industrial Revolution was a cultural shift towards valuing and disseminating useful knowledge. In Bourgeois Dignity, D. N. McCloskey makes a similar argument—that the unprecedented economic growth of the modern era was primarily due to a shift in societal values and rhetoric, particularly the rise of liberalism and the revaluation of the “bourgeois” virtues. Leigh might reply that these changes weren’t “sudden,” but in the long history of humanity which this book covers they do appear to be rather sudden. Instead of grappling with these critical ideas about what sparked the “Great Enrichment,” Leigh’s chapter on “The Industrial Revolution and the Wealth of Nations” tells a much simpler and more compact story. It brings in important ideas from Adam Smith, Jeremy Bentham, William Stanley Jevons, John Stuart Mill and even Frédéric Bastiat—along with interesting thoughts on the importance of clocks and mirrors, among other things. Writing a short history like this is a delicate balancing act. Another balancing act is temporal. The chronological plot of The Shortest History moves very quickly at first, before decelerating. One senses that Leigh really cares much more about the present, its immediate roots, and his agenda for the future. Surprisingly, to me at least, it takes only fifteen short pages to get from the dawn of humankind to the year 600 AD and we zip to the beginning of the twentieth century in another forty-eight pages.

…..

However, a far more glaring omission comes in Leigh’s discussion of the Great Depression—which, like much else in the book, is very US-centric (despite the fact that the publisher is British and the author is Australian). The narrative of the Great Depression opens with and stresses the stock market crash and brings in other causes like the paradox of thrift, the Smoot-Hawley tariff, and immigration policy. It omits mention of weaknesses in the banking sector due to unit-banking laws, the contraction of the money supply, the missteps of the Federal Reserve, and problems with interwar gold standard as emphasized by Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz in their Monetary History of the United States and Barry Eichengreen in Golden Fetters. These omissions border on malpractice. Did Leigh throw away the memo when Ben Bernanke said, “Regarding the Great Depression . . . we did it. We’’e very sorry. . . . We won’t do it again”?

In addition, Leigh doesn’t address why the Great Depression persisted so long. He could have mentioned Robert Higgs’s arguments about “regime uncertainty,” paralyzing investors or at least discussed a few of the policies that stifled the recovery, especially the National Industrial Recovery Act. He certainly has room to do so. In a one-page box on Sadie Alexander, the first African American woman to receive a doctorate in economics, Leigh mentions her criticisms of the NIRA, which “boosted wages in certain sectors” so that “employers in those industries fired black workers and hired whites in their place” (96). But he doesn’t mention that the above equilibrium wages of the National Recovery Administration caused overall employment to collapse and pushed up prices causing sales to fall as shown by economic historians like Jason Taylor. The fuller story simply clashes too much with his overall thrust that government solves problems like these. (The chapter also repeats the conventional wisdom that Weimar Germany was crippled by enormous reparations under the Treaty of Versailles. This argument is contested by Max Hantke and Mark Spoerer in “The Imposed Gift of Versailles: The Fiscal Effects of Restricting the Size of Germany’s Armed Forces, 1924–29.” They find that the net effect of the Treaty’s stipulations on the German central budgets was either much lower than previously thought or even positive, as reductions in military spending offset all or more than all of the reparations bill.)

The Editorial Board of the Washington Post wisely urges Republicans to resist the call to end the filibuster. A slice:

The irony is that Democrats who tried so hard to get rid of the filibuster under President Joe Biden are now taking advantage of it. Joe Manchin (West Virginia) and Kyrsten Sinema (Arizona) stopped Democrats from “going nuclear” in 2022 — and were effectively forced into retirement. Perhaps Democrats will have the votes to nuke the filibuster the next time they control the Senate, but they’d prefer if Republicans did it for them.

… yet Chuck Schumer’s contempt for the American people’s intelligence is so low that he supposes that we’re too stupid to understand that the filibuster still exists.

Juliette Sellgren talks with Derek Scissors about China’s economic policy.

Travis Fisher details “some inconvenient truths for climate radicals.”

Gabriela Calderon de Burgos and Marcos Falcone urge Argentina to dollarize.

The failure of Macron.”

{ 0 comments }

On Securing Sources of Supplies

Here’s a letter to the Wall Street Journal.

Editor:

You report that, in response to increased riskiness of trading with China, General Motors “has quietly seeded the revival of the domestic magnet industry, locking down supply amid trade tensions” (“GM’s Rare-Earth Gamble Pays Off as China Tightens Magnet Exports,” October 13). This news is further evidence against the case for high tariffs.

Protectionists routinely assert that free trade leaves our ‘supply chains’ vulnerable and, therefore, government must restrict our trade in order to ensure that we’re not dependent on unreliable foreign sources of supplies. But as G.M.’s actions show, the market gives private firms strong incentives to take steps to better secure their supply sources when the riskiness of relying on foreign suppliers becomes too great.

Nearly all U.S. imports are purchased by businesses that either will retail these goods to American consumers or use these goods as inputs in production that occurs on American soil. No one has incentives as strong as do these businesses to correctly assess the riskiness of relying on foreign suppliers, and to reduce this reliance when (and only when) that riskiness rises to dangerous levels. To suppose that politicians and bureaucrats, with no economic skin in the game, know better than do the private businesses that purchase imports if and when foreign sources of supplies are becoming too risky is preposterous.

Sincerely,
Donald J. Boudreaux
Professor of Economics
and
Martha and Nelson Getchell Chair for the Study of Free Market Capitalism at the Mercatus Center
George Mason University
Fairfax, VA 22030

{ 0 comments }

Some Links

GMU Econ alum Dan Mitchell pushes back against Matthew Lynn’s uninformed indictment of economists on trade. A slice:

Some economists overstated the damage of trade taxes. And some of them may have been motivated by anti-Trump sentiments.

But that doesn’t change the fact that protectionism is bad for the economy.

Here are five points to keep in mind. The first three apply to all policy analysis and the last two apply specifically to trade policy.

  1. Economists are lousy forecasters. If they actually knew how to predict the economy, they could make millions or even billions of dollars in financial markets. What economists should do – and can do – is assess whether a particular policy will cause more growth or less growth.
  2. It is very difficult to dramatically change the economy, so even a very good policy may only cause the economy to grow by, say, an extra 2/10ths of 1 percent per year (and vice-versa for a bad policy). Of course, because of compounding, even small changes can lead to big long-term differences in prosperity.
  3. The policy lever that is most likely to cause a recession isn’t trade policy or tax policy. It’s monetary policy. Almost all recent economic downturns (the COVID lockdown being the exception) were caused by misguided boom-bust policies by the Federal Reserve.
  4. Regarding trade, there are two major measures of economic liberty (Economic Freedom of the World and Index of Economic Freedom) and trade only accounts for about 20 percent of a nation’s grade. So it is easy to have bad policy in one area that is offset by good policy in other areas (and vice-versa).
  5. Some estimates of serious economic damage were made after Trump’s so-called Liberation Day trade taxes were announced. After the adverse reaction in financial markets, Trump backed off. The chart shows that Trump has made trade policy worse, but the overall tax increase on trade is not nearly as bad as originally planned, so it should not be a surprise that the damage has not been as severe.

The Wall Street Journal reports evidence of an economic phenomenon that should be obvious, but instead is one that is typically missed even by economists: Securing sources of supply against international risks is often done privately – that is, by private firms whose self-interest drives them to take such steps when prudent. General Motors doesn’t need Donald Trump, Joe Biden, Robert Lighthizer, or any other protectionist to tell it how to do its business. A slice:

Last week China introduced new draconian restrictions on rare-earth magnet exports, a reminder of its power to disrupt global supply chains—and cause American manufacturers, including carmakers, to halt production.

American auto companies have long relied on China for the magnets, which are essential for making everything from electric motors to headlights and windshield wipers

But today, one automaker, General Motors GM has less reason to fret.

In 2021, GM made the bold bet of investing in rare-earth magnet production in the U.S., as part of a broader effort to cut its reliance on China for parts, components and materials. As a result, in the coming months, GM is now set to be the only U.S. automaker with a large direct supply of American-made rare-earth magnets from multiple factories.
It has been a risky bet. GM had to commit to long-term purchase agreements with new suppliers, in some cases relatively unproven ones, whose magnets are more expensive than the Chinese ones.

Writing in the Washington Post, Johan Norberg asks: “Is it America’s fate to decline and fall?”

The ancient Greek historian Thucydides spoke of two mindsets — the Athenian’s, eager to venture out into the world to acquire something new, and the Spartan’s, intent on staying home to guard what he already had.

Broadly speaking, the Athenian spirit is associated with golden ages. When civilizations were open to influences from merchants and migrants, and when they let people experiment with new ideas and innovations, they prospered. This required tolerance of pluralism and surprise, as well as institutions and norms to restrain rulers’ arbitrary use of power.

Indeed, modern China offers another example of the importance of such a mentality. Its rise has been Athenian in character, beginning with Deng Xiaoping’s 1978 “reform and opening up,” when the country embraced entrepreneurship and trade. Xi’s recent Spartan crackdown on freedoms and private enterprise threatens to undo those gains. Productivity has slowed, debt has soared and confidence has ebbed. It’s hard to see the East rising much further that way.

It is difficult to uphold open societies for long. When cultures turned anxious, curiosity gave way to control and open trade to barriers. The populace tended to long for strongmen and hunt for scapegoats. In times of trouble, the Abbasid Caliphate and Renaissance Italy imposed orthodoxy and persecuted heretics. Even open-minded Athens sentenced Socrates to death. In 1672, the usually tolerant Dutch lynched Johan de Witt, the statesman who had led them to prosperity, and purged their universities of Enlightenment thinkers.

The parallels with our world are unsettling. Since the turn of the millennium, the dominant Western mentality has shifted from Athenian to Spartan. We have endured terrorism, wars, a pandemic and economic turmoil, while social media has intensified polarization and politicians have learned how to divide and conquer.

The world looks increasingly dangerous, and the result has been a backlash against trade and migration. That threatens to cut us off from the world’s talents and technologies, recalling the Chinese Ming dynasty’s 15th-century ban on international trade. They sought stability; they got stagnation.

At the same time, two reactive forces to modern pluralism have developed: a hard nationalist right and a radical illiberal left. They present themselves as opposites but are united in their obsession with identity politics and a dream of sameness, in which alternative ideas and cultures are seen as threats. For years, the illiberal left tried to cancel dissenting voices on campuses and in academic curriculums. Now the Trump movement seeks to impose its own orthodoxy, threatening universities, law firms and media companies with government power.

This ambition to enforce one idea on everyone is always presented as a call for unity. In practice, it creates a zero-sum game that fuels conflict. The assassinations of conservative activist Charlie Kirk and Democratic Minnesota state representative Melissa Hortman, the Jan. 6, 2021, attack on the U.S. Capitol and the repeated attempts on President Donald Trump’s life show how quickly angry tribalism can descend into violence.

The Editorial Board of the Wall Street Journal argues that California’s “mandated climate disclosures violate the First Amendment.” A slice:

California Gov. Gavin Newsom, like every politician, claims to be a champion of free speech. Then why is his state arguing in court that progressive climate orthodoxy trumps free speech?

The answer is because the Democratic left wants to force businesses to disclose publicly their putative climate risks and CO2 emissions. The Biden Securities and Exchange Commission’s effort to compel such disclosures hit a dead end when President Trump took office.

Enter Mr. Newsom, who is now leading the campaign. California law requires companies with more than $500 million in annual revenue that “do business” in the state—which can mean having a single employee or contractor in the state—to detail how speculative climate-related risks could affect their businesses.

Congratulations to Joel Mokyr, Philippe Aghion, and Peter Howitt.

In response to Pope Leo’s economically uninformed assertion that about free markets and poverty alleviation, Jeff Jacoby tweets:

Who ever claimed that “a free market economy will automatically solve the problem of poverty”? No rational capitalist would ever say such a thing. What is true is that free market economies generate far more wealth, so that far, far less of society ends up trapped in poverty.

{ 0 comments }

Quotation of the Day…

… is from page 38 of Edwin Cannan’s 1917 paper, “The Influence of the War on Commercial Policy,” which is Chapter 2 of the 1917 volume, Some Economic Aspects of International Relations:

Much of [the dislike for reductions of particular kinds of employment] comes simply from a fundamental misconception which leads people to suppose that labour itself is wanted instead of merely the things which labour produces, and which are not wanted because labour produces them, but are produced by labour because they are wanted. The habit of talking of each particular industry leads people insensibly into the belief that the industry directly supports or maintains those who follow it in such wise that a diminution in its amount would diminish the whole society’s means of maintaining its numbers. If we say that bootmaking supports bootmakers, we are apt to fall into thinking that if we grew boots with as little trouble as fingernails and with no more nourishment than at present, society, to be as well off as it is, would have to be less numerous by the whole number of persons employed in bootmaking. With some muddle of this kind in our minds we become inclined to regard every “expansion of industry” (in the sense of more labour being devoted to any particular kind of production) as a good, and every contraction as an evil. We are prone to rejoice indiscriminately over every increase of numbers employed in any trade, and to mourn indiscriminately over every decrease. We even sometimes go further, and rejoice not only over an absolute increase of numbers but over an increasing percentage of the whole number being employed in a trade, while at the same time, in defiance of elementary arithmetic, we mourn over a decreasing percentage employed in another trade!

DBx: Sadly, pundits and politicians continue in 2025 to spread the myth that labor is an end in itself rather than a means to the end of consumption. Sufficient proof that labor is not an end in itself is the fact that individuals must be paid to work. Yet mysteriously, this universal reality – namely, that individuals must be paid to work – nevertheless fails to be noticed by many pundits and politicians as proof positive against the proposition that working is a end in itself.

{ 0 comments }

Sorry, But Pope Leo Is Mistaken

Here’s a letter to a new correspondent.

Mr. T__:

Thanks for sharing Sohrab Ahmari’s tweet, which I’d not otherwise have noticed.

It is, frankly, pathetically inept. In order to criticize the pro-free-market Acton Institute, Ahmari favorably quotes Pope Leo’s assertion that “pseudo-scientific data are invoked to support the claim that a free market economy will automatically solve the problem of poverty.”

I’ve not read the document in which the Pope makes this remark, but I doubt that the Pope – whatever his merits as a theologian – did a thorough survey of the relevant economic literature.

First, by using the word “automatically,” the Pope slays a straw man. I know of no serious scholar who claims that the free market “will automatically solve the problem of poverty.” From Adam Smith through Milton Friedman and Deirdre McCloskey, credible scholars have recognized that individual initiative plays a significant role in determining the particular economic ‘outcomes’ of individuals within market economies.

Second, the scientific evidence is overwhelming that the more economically free is a society, the greater is the material wealth not only of the mean or median person (and household) in that society, but also of the persons (and households) in the lowest deciles of those societies’ income ‘distributions.’ Just a few days ago the Fraser Institute released its Economic Freedom of the World: 2025 Annual Report. I urge Ahmari – and the Pope – to study this document carefully. It’s social science in the truest and best sense of the term, and there’s nothing pseudo-scientific about the data presented there.

This report shows a clear, positive correlation between economic freedom and various measures of material well-being. For example (quoting the Report):

– “The rate of poverty in the least free quartile [of countries] is about 25 times greater than it is in the freest”;

– “The level of income earned by the poorest 10% of the population is much higher in countries with greater economic freedom”;

– “People in the freest quartile live about 17 years longer than those in the least-free quartile”;

– “In the least-free countries, infants die at nearly 10 times the rate as they do in the freest countries.”

These last two facts, I should think, would be weighed especially heavily by people who are pro-life.

Perhaps the Pope and Ahmari will insist that these data are “pseudo-scientific” – in which case I’d ask them to offer in response their own data. I’m quite sure that they have none that begin to hold a scientific candle to the data in this Report.

I end with one other relevant fact: patterns of immigration. Most immigrants, if they are allowed, flee from countries that are economically less free to countries that are economically more free. Economically free countries (stupidly, in my opinion) struggle to limit immigration; economically unfree countries struggle to limit emigration. This reality ought to carry more than a little weight with the pontiff and his flock.

Sincerely,
Donald J. Boudreaux
Professor of Economics
and
Martha and Nelson Getchell Chair for the Study of Free Market Capitalism at the Mercatus Center
George Mason University
Fairfax, VA 22030

{ 0 comments }

Some Links

The Wall Street Journal‘s Editorial Board decries what it rightly calls the “madness” of today’s bipartisan lawfare – madness that terribly corrodes the rule of law. Two slices:

Letitia James campaigned on a pledge to get President Trump, accused him of lying about his assets to obtain favorable loan terms, and won a whopping financial penalty that was thrown out after appeal. Mr. Trump campaigned on a pledge to exact retribution, and now his Justice Department accuses Ms. James of lying on mortgage forms to obtain favorable loan terms, a case that could be thrown out before trial.

The mirror image of these two best of enemies is instructive. Ms. James’s case was destructive lawfare. So is Mr. Trump’s. The question is how to get the spiral to stop before we all go down the drain.

…..

Worried about Mr. Trump’s promises of retribution, President Biden issued blanket pardons on his way out the door. After taking his revenge, will Mr. Trump have to do the same on Jan. 20, 2029? This is madness.

The better path for the country is for both parties to conclude that the lawfare of recent years has been a historic mistake, and that nobody benefits from becoming a banana republic. Mutual assured legal destruction is no way to run a great nation.

The Editorial Board of the Washington Post warns New Yorkers that Zohran Mamdani is about to take them on a very expensive and unpleasant ride. A slice:

Plenty of cities have eliminated bus fares, but it always comes at a cost. Olympia, Washington, did so in 2020 to avoid having to upgrade their fare-card readers but hiked the local sales tax. That means everyone pays, whether they ride or not. Other free systems have drawn criticism for becoming magnets of crime and vandalism, such as Portland, Oregon, where fare-free transit was discontinued in 2012.

Issuing another warning to New Yorkers is C. Jarrett Dieterle – in this case that expanding its “minimum wage” coverage will further reduce the employment opportunities of low-skilled New Yorkers. A slice:

New York’s experiment with delivery driver wage mandates hasn’t gone well. Pay went up after the 2023 rule kicked in, but so did prices—and many drivers left the market altogether. The city saw an 8 percent drop in its delivery workforce, while food delivery costs rose 10 percent, including a 12 percent jump in restaurant prices and a staggering 58 percent spike in app fees. Tips, meanwhile, plunged 47 percent. Platforms even started capping drivers—at one point, Uber Eats reported more than 27,000 New Yorkers were on their driver waitlist.

Ian Vásquez applauds the award of the 2025 Nobel Peace Prize to María Corina Machado. A slice:

The Nobel Committee made an excellent choice. Maria Corina Machado is one of the world’s most admirable leaders. After a quarter century of opposing Venezuela’s Chavista regime, she emerged in the past couple of years as the clear leader of an opposition that, until then, had been internally divisive and ineffective in challenging the regime.

Maria Corina, a sophisticated classical liberal and longtime friend of the Cato Institute, achieved several important goals that took the regime by surprise and that make her unique among Venezuela’s opposition leaders. First, she united Venezuela under a single ballot during the presidential elections last July (as I wrote here). She had the overwhelming support of Venezuelans but was illegally disqualified from running for office, so she supported Edmundo Gonzalez in her place.

MIT alum Rep. Thomas Massie (R-KY) tweets: (HT Scott Lincicome)

The surest way to screw up the world’s best technical school is to let feds tell them how to run it.

Congrats to my alma mater for turning down a bribe to let the executive branch dictate what happens on its campus.

A lot of things are wrong in 🇺🇸, but MIT is not one of them.

Terry Anderson and my GMU Econ colleague Thomas Stratmann explore this: “Doing Business on Indian Reservations: Tribal Business Owners’ Perspectives on Entrepreneurship.” Here’s the abstract:

This paper reports insights from focus group discussions from Montana reservations, which provide insights and perspectives on the experiences of Native American entrepreneurs. The narratives from these discussions highlight the challenges the current regulatory context poses for entrepreneurial activities and their communities. The participants spoke of regulatory unpredictability and inefficiency, resulting in uncertainty faced by business owners and thus not impeding economic prosperity. The discussions also revealed a disconnect between tribal governments and community members, characterized by a lack of transparency and accountability. Judicial independence emerged as another significant concern. These insights from the focus groups suggest a path forward for more economic growth and prosperity for reservation communities.

At his Facebook page, Chris Lingle shares an extensive list of Javier Milei’s accomplishments in Argentina.

Douglas Irwin’s remarkable 2017 history of U.S. trade policy – Clashing Over Commerce – is now available free on-line. (My hope is that tomorrow the Nobel Prize committee will announce that Doug and his teacher Jagdish Bhagwati have won the 2025 Prize in Economics. A three-way share with Arvind Panagariya would also be good.)

{ 0 comments }

Quotation of the Day…

… is from page 185 of Edwin Cannan’s 1902 address to the British Association (Section F) – an address titled “The Practical Utility of Economic Science” – as this address is reprinted in the 1912 collection of some of Cannan’s essays, The Economic Outlook (E. Cannan, ed.):

The people who are most anxious to obstruct changes in the channels of trade which are coming about of themselves because they are profitable, are often extremely anxious to promote changes which will not come about of themselves because they are not profitable.

DBx: Yep.

It’s common, for example, for economic nationalists, with one breath, to decry the need for workers to adjust to the changes that necessarily accompany economic growth, and then with the next breath advocate government-imposed schemes to attempt to re-engineer the economy in order to make it more pleasing to the intellectual conceits of economic nationalists. The implicit – indeed, unconscious – assumption is that the need to adjust to changes brought on by market forces is excessively burdensome and not worthwhile, while the need to adjust to changes brought on by government intervention are easy and worthwhile. No one, to my knowledge, has ever bothered to explain why this difference might prevail in reality.

{ 0 comments }

Bonus Quotation of the Day…

… is the concluding paragraph (on page 38) of Robert Lawson’s and Matthew Mitchell’s superb essay “US Economic Freedom in a Trade War,” which is Chapter 2 of the newly released Economic Freedom of the World: 2025 Annual Report:

For more than a century, the United States has been the most prosperous country in the world. Americans represent just 4.2% of the global population yet they produce more than 26% of global GDP. US median income is nearly nine times the global average and the US poverty rate is a fraction of the global rate. This prosperity was built on a foundation of economic freedom. And that freedom is eroding thanks to President Trump’s trade war.

{ 0 comments }

The Illogic That Is Protectionism

Here’s a letter to the New York Post.

Editor:

Perhaps a good case can be made that, to strengthen America’s security, the U.S. government ought to restrict our trade with the Chinese. But such a case should be economically coherent. Elaine Dezenski’s case is not (“Trump is fighting a historic clash of civilizations against China — here’s how he could win it,” October 10).

She writes: “China limits its critical exports to weaken our defenses, it also floods the world with overproduced cars and heavily subsidized steel, shutting out market-oriented producers.”

In a single sentence, Ms. Dezenski asserts that China hurts us both by exporting too little to us and by exporting too much to us. Which is it?

If, as Ms. Dezenski implies with her comment about cars and steel, domestic industries suffer and dangerously shrink when our producers compete freely with low-priced imports, Beijing does us a favor by withholding “critical exports.” This move by Beijing raises the profitability of expanding U.S. production of “critical” goods such as rare-earth materials.

But if, as Ms. Dezenski also claims, we would benefit from increased access to “critical” goods from China, surely we benefit also from increased access to the likes of cars and steel from China.

It makes no sense to argue that Beijing hurts us by decreasing Chinese exports of “critical” goods, and also by increasing Chinese exports of less-critical goods – increased exports, take note, that enable more of our resources to be devoted to the production of “critical” goods and services.

Sincerely,
Donald J. Boudreaux
Professor of Economics
and
Martha and Nelson Getchell Chair for the Study of Free Market Capitalism at the Mercatus Center
George Mason University
Fairfax, VA 22030

{ 0 comments }