≡ Menu

In my latest essay for AIER, I explain what would happen were Trump to apply to Mar-a-Lago the same economic ideas and policies about trade that he’s applying to the United States economy. This little tale, while fictional about Mar-a-Lago, is quite factual about the destructive consequences that Trump’s twisted and wrongheaded ideas about trade would deliver to Mar-a-Lago – and what they would deliver to America.

Here’s my conclusion (but do read the whole story):

If the above tale sounds fantastically unrealistic, that’s because it is. No one – literally no one, rich or poor, not even Donald Trump – would even think about attempting to conduct his or her household’s economic affairs as described above. And yet, Trump is actually trying to conduct America’s economic affairs in a similar way. The economic ‘logic,’ such as it is, that motivates his invocation of emergency powers to impose tariffs rests on Trump’s belief that U.S. goods trade deficits with individual countries is an economic emergency, and evidence that foreign exporters or governments have long gotten away with economically ripping America off.

If it would make economic sense for Trump to run Mar-a-Lago in the fantastical way portrayed above, then Trump’s “Liberation Day” tariffs might make economic sense for America. But if it makes no sense – if it is downright crazy – for Trump to run Mar-a-Lago as described above, then his “Liberation Day” tariffs are the height of economic insanity. And they are.

{ 0 comments }

Some Links

Scott Lincicome explains that “Trump’s new furniture tariffs are (almost) everything wrong with U.S. trade policy today.” Two slices:

Maybe the tariffs’ most absurd aspect is that they’re being imposed on wood products for supposed “national security” reasons, pursuant to Section 232 of the Trade Expansion Act of 1962. That law, you may recall, is also the foundation for Trump’s tariffs on steel, aluminum, automotive goods, and copper, as well as pending cases on semiconductors, drones, minerals, heavy-duty trucks, and a range of other products that have at least a plausible connection to the production of U.S. defense goods and military preparedness more broadly. Those cases have major practical and economic flaws, but one could say they pass a “smell test” for some sort of security-related nexus.

As I explained when the wood tariffs case was first announced, however, there’s no plausible case for wood imports to be a national security risk:

If war broke out tomorrow, there’d be zero concern about American “dependence” on foreign lumber or furniture, and domestic sources would be quickly and easily acquired. (We have lots of trees, and these industries neither involve advanced technology nor are highly capital intensive.) Furthermore, nearly half of total US lumber imports come from Canada, a longstanding military ally and close trading partner.

The new Federal Register notice announcing the tariffs reinforces this conclusion. It simply asserts that wood imports are a threat because they’re used by the “Department of War” and in “critical infrastructure sectors” that, if destroyed, “would have a debilitating effect on the national security, economic welfare, or national public health or safety of the United States.” Yet, even leaving aside my initial point (and that freer access to low-cost wood from Canada and elsewhere would actually boost U.S. rebuilding efforts), the FR notice’s very next paragraph acknowledges that “the United States possesses ample raw materials and industrial capacity to meet domestic wood products demand.” In other words, even granting the absurd premise that wood imports might be a security threat, American companies are currently providing the wood the nation (supposedly) needs.

……

Research from UBS indicates that the new Section 232 tariffs on wood products will add another $1,000 to the cost of building a home, on top of the $8,000 in tariff costs we’ve already seen this year. That might not sound like a lot, but—as we discussed last year—it can have an effect on the margins, discouraging the construction of lower-end starter homes (where costs matter more) or pushing buyers out of certain local markets entirely—especially when coupled with land use, labor, permitting, and other policies that further boost U.S. construction and housing costs. As the New York Times notes, the hit will be particularly bad for lower-income consumers “who buy premade cabinets, vanities or mass-market furniture from the Home Depot and other big-box stores” and in California, where “so many homeowners are rebuilding after devastating wildfires.” And, as usual, the tariffs directly contradict another Trump administration priority: boosting homeownership and housing affordability.

I guess the White House will stow that “national housing emergency” they’d been considering.

The Competitive Enterprise Institute’s Jeremy Lott, writing at National Review, calls on Congress to rein in Trump’s seizure of Congressional tariff-setting authority. A slice:

H. L. Mencken, the Sage of Baltimore, grounded American democracy in the notion that the “common people know what they want and deserve to get it good and hard.” Critics have used that intuition to throw tariff shocks back in the faces of Trump backers. “You voted for this,” comes the refrain.

That is not entirely true or fair. Yes, enough people in enough states voted to send Donald Trump back to the Oval Office after one term spent in the penalty box, but they did so for different reasons and without good alternatives, at least on this issue. The Biden administration, whose policies Trump opponent and Vice President Kamala Harris embraced, was hardly a champion of free trade.

President Joe Biden kept in place many of Trump’s first-term tariffs and also enacted additional ones. Last September, Biden’s Office of the United States Trade Representative announced more China sanctions: new tariffs on metals, microchips, electric vehicles, batteries, critical minerals, and other tech and medical products.

Even the Biden administration’s feints in the direction of free trade were weak and did nothing to pull nations away from China’s sphere of influence and toward the U.S. In December, the first agreement under the U.S.-Taiwan Initiative on 21st Century Trade became law. “The agreement is not a conventional free trade agreement and it does not address market access issues,” explained Sheng Lu, a business professor at the University of Delaware. Rather, it continued the lamentable trend of making trade agreements about many other issues — so that free trade gets squeezed out.

The tariffs leveled by the first Trump administration were demonstrably bad for the U.S. economy. “The full incidence of the tariffs has fallen on domestic consumers and importers so far, and our estimates imply a reduction in aggregate US real income of $1.4 billion per month by the end of 2018,” wrote economists Mary Amiti, Stephen J. Redding, and David E. Weinstein in the Journal of Economic Perspectives.

Bradley Smith and Eric Wang report this good news:

Remember the Internal Revenue Service scandal of 2013, when it came out that the IRS under the Obama administration had targeted conservative nonprofits for harassment? In a little-noticed but immensely consequential First Amendment decision Sept. 30, a federal judge ruled that the IRS regulations on nonprofits’ political activity are unconstitutional.

It’s a major free-speech victory nearly 15 years in the making. In the case, Freedom Path v. IRS, Judge Jia M. Cobb, a Biden appointee, concluded what the nonprofit community has long known: The IRS rules concerning whether certain nonprofit organizations have engaged in too much political activity are unworkable and unconstitutionally vague.

At the heart of the case is Section 501(c)(4) of the tax code, which mainly addresses social-welfare organizations and advocacy groups. Under IRS rules, a 501(c)(4) organization must be “primarily engaged” in promoting the “common good and general welfare” of society, but not “political campaign” activity.

The problem Freedom Path and other 501(c)(4)s face is simple: They can’t tell what’s legal. The IRS has never defined how much political activity is too much. And even if a group knew the amount of political activity allowed as a percentage of total activities, it still wouldn’t know what qualifies as political. The agency uses an open-ended 11-factor test to determine what counts as “political activity,” without explaining how these factors are weighted or applied.

Judge Cobb ruled that these twin deficiencies “exhibit signs of impermissible vagueness. Taken together, they cross the line into unconstitutionality.” The judge also found a record of “selective enforcement” that “solidifies this vagueness finding,” pointing to the IRS’s targeting of tea-party-aligned 501(c)(4)s during the early 2010s.

…..

The Freedom Path decision presents Congress with an opportunity to stop the IRS from using the tax code to police political debate.

Damon Root is right that “Amy Coney Barrett is right to reject ‘common good constitutionalism.'” A slice:

Barrett is wise to reject “common good constitutionalism.” The innocuous-sounding concept largely stems from the work of right-wing Harvard law professor Adrian Vermeule, who has urged conservatives to reject originalism and embrace “authoritative rule for the common good” in its place.

What counts as the “common good”? For Vermeule, it seems to mean aggressive government action in support of various right-wing goals, all to be carried out free from any pesky restrictions imposed by the original meaning of the Constitution.

Chris Edwards makes clear that air-traffic control need not be a governmental operation. A slice:

The core problem is that America’s ATC is run by the government. It does not have to be—dozens of nations have separated their ATC from government budgets and bureaucracies. Canada, for example, privatized its ATC in 1996 as a self-funded nonprofit corporation. The system earns revenues by direct charges on aviation users, without the need for subsidies.

The US ATC system, run by the Federal Aviation Administration (FAA), suffers from politicized decisions on investment, employment, and restructuring. By contrast, the private Canadian system has delivered safe, efficient, and innovative services for three decades.

Bob Graboyes reflects on the two years since October 7th.

{ 0 comments }

Quotation of the Day…

… is from page 362 of the original edition of Walter Lippmann’s sometimes deeply flawed but profoundly insightful and important 1937 book, The Good Society:

The hankering for schemes and systems and comprehensive organization is the wistfulness of an immature philosophy which has not come to terms with reality, no less when the conservators of vested interests would stabilize the modern economy in statu quo by protective laws and monopolistic schemes than when the revolutionist makes blueprints of a world composed of planned national economies “coordinated” by a world-planning authority. Neither takes any more account of reality than if he were studying landscape architecture with a view to making a formal garden out of the Brazilian jungle.

For the greater the society, the higher and more variable the standards of life, the more diversified the energies of its people for invention, enterprise, and adaptation, the more certain it is that the social order cannot be planned ex cathedra or governed by administrative command.

{ 0 comments }

Some Links

The Editorial Board of the Wall Street Journal explains what shouldn’t – but, alas, what today nevertheless does – need explaining: America makes immigrants better, and immigrants make America better. Two slices:

Welcoming immigrants to the U.S. is out of fashion on the political right these days, even for those who enter the U.S. legally. That’s short-sighted for America’s future prosperity, as this week’s news about the annual Nobel prize winners in the sciences shows again.

Six U.S. residents are among the nine winners in this year’s three Nobel science categories, and three of those six are immigrants. Three U.S.-based professors swept the physics prize, including Michel Devoret, an immigrant from France, and John Clarke, who came to the U.S. from the United Kingdom. They shared the prize with native-born American John Martinis for “quantum mechanical tunnelling.”

Omar Yaghi, an immigrant from Jordan, shared the prize in chemistry with an Australian and a Japanese national. They won for what the Nobel committee called “the development of metal-organic frameworks.”

…..

Some of our readers will sniff that these are mere anecdotes and say the Trump White House supports legal immigration. Sorry, anecdotes matter because the contributions of individuals matter. And the restrictionists in the White House are trying to shrink even legal immigration too.

See its plan to make H-1B visas too expensive for all but the largest companies, and the campaign to reduce the number of foreign students at U.S. universities. This year’s Nobelists, like winners every year, were attracted to the U.S. in part because of the opportunities at great research universities. One inevitable if hard-to-calculate price of the Trump campaigns against immigration and the U.S. academy is that an unknown number of future potential prize winners will choose to study elsewhere, or return home after they have a degree.

Nobel prizes in the sciences are the result of intellectual capital built over decades of hard work and research. The U.S. will get fewer in the future if the Trump Administration won’t welcome legal immigrants and refugees.

Also explaining what shouldn’t – but, alas, what today nevertheless does – need explaining (this time about the damage done by rent control) is Kevin Lavery.

Scott Lincicome tweets:

Well well well: “Trump Excludes Generics From Big Pharma Tariff Plan

Good news for American consumers (patients), but a major Trump reversal on generics and an admission that his tariffs do, in fact, raise US prices.

GMU Econ alum Adam Michel details “six reasons not to extend Obamacare subsidies.” (HT David Henderson)

Sen. Rand Paul (R-KY) powerfully argues that “the Constitution does not allow the president to unilaterally blow suspected drug smugglers to smithereens.” A slice:

Critics of this whole terrorist labelling charade, such as Matthew Petti at Reason, explain that: “In practice, that means that a ‘terrorist’ is whoever the executive branch decides to label one.”

While no law dictates such, once people are labelled as terrorists, they appear to no longer be eligible for any sort of due process.

The blow-them-to-smithereens crowd, at this point, will loudly voice their opinion that people in international waters whom we label as terrorists deserve no due process. Vice President Vance asserts: “There are people who are bringing—literal terrorists—who are bringing deadly drugs into our country.”

Which, of course, raises the questions:

  1. Who labelled them and with what evidence?
  2. What are their names, and what specifically shows their membership and guilt?

The blow-them-to-smithereens crowd also conveniently ignores the fact that death is generally not the penalty for drug smuggling.

George Will warns of the dangers posed to the world by Vladimir Putin. A slice:

Poland and Romania have experienced harassing drones. In multiple instances, “shadow ships” (worldwide, the “shadow fleet” of ships that conceal their identities and activities numbers about 1,000) have been accused of cutting undersea cables crucial to Europe commercial and military infrastructure.

Jack Nicastro reminds us that government isn’t the only source of economic data.

Historian David Beito looks back on FDR’s authoritarian use of government ownership of the electromagnetic spectrum to violate Americans’ First Amendment rights. A slice:

Prior to the 1927 creation of the Federal Radio Commission (the predecessor of the Federal Communications Commission, or FCC), radio was arguably freer than the printing press. Short-range audio broadcasts not only gave listeners mass entertainment but also provided a way to share and access diverse opinions: socialists, labor unions, religious evangelists, and political populists. Well-publicized problems of interference between frequencies were often engineered politically to bolster calls for regulation, but court rulings were sorting through confusion. Affirming the doctrine of prior use, courts were able to determine de facto ownership in the electromagnetic spectrum.

Roosevelt was determined to silence dissenting voices on the radio. He adeptly manipulated the revolving door of regulators and industry executives and executed behind-the-scenes intrigue using intermediaries to conceal the appearance of censorship while embracing its effects.

By 1933, big broadcasters eagerly aligned themselves with the new administration, and in many cases became regulators themselves. Former FRC commissioner — CBS vice president — Henry A. Bellows was a Democrat and Harvard classmate of FDR’s. In his official role, he promised to reject any broadcast “that in any way was critical of any policy of the Administration,” and announced that all stations were “at the disposal of President Roosevelt and his administration.” Bellows specified that CBS had a duty to support the president, right or wrong, and privately assured presidential press secretary Stephen Early that “the close contact between you and the broadcasters has tremendous possibilities of value to the administration, and as a life-long Democrat, I want to pledge my best efforts in making this cooperation successful.”

{ 0 comments }

Quotation of the Day…

is from page 325 of Gordon Wood’s great 1991 book, The Radicalism of the American Revolution:

In the end, no banks, no government, no institutions could have created the American economic miracle of these years. America suddenly emerged a prosperous, scrambling, enterprising society not because the Constitution was created or because a few leaders formed a national bank, but because ordinary people, hundreds of thousands of them, began working harder to make money and “get ahead.” Americans seemed to be a people totally absorbed in the individual pursuit of money. “Enterprise,” “improvement,” and “energy” were everywhere extolled in the press.

DBx: Note that Wood could have added also that this growth was not due to protective tariffs.

Wood’s observation about American history lends further credence to Deirdre McCloskey’s thesis that pro-commercial ideas – and, importantly, favorable talking and writing about commerce and market-tested innovation – are the chief source of what Adam Smith called “the wealth of nations.”

{ 0 comments }

Yet Another Open Letter to Tariff Man

October 8, 2025

Mr. Donald J. Trump
President, Executive Branch
United States Government
1600 Pennsylvania Ave., NW
Washington, DC 20500

Mr. Trump:

About your trade negotiations with Canadian officials you say that “we don’t like to compete because we sort of hurt each other when we compete” (“Trade deal between Canada, U.S. will likely require more time,” October 7).

Why is your opinion of American businesses and workers so low? What makes you think that American producers that compete openly against foreign producers are fated to suffer such serious harm that they can thrive only if coddled with special privileges and protections? You obviously believe that your fellow Americans are inept and spinelessly averse to risk.

And what about American consumers? Why do you ignore the suffering they endure when businesses are shielded from competition? Or do you suppose that forcing Americans to pay higher prices for lower-quality goods paves a path to American greatness if doing so enables American producers to survive without having to work hard to satisfy their customers?

Sincerely,
Donald J. Boudreaux
Professor of Economics
and
Martha and Nelson Getchell Chair for the Study of Free Market Capitalism at the Mercatus Center
George Mason University
Fairfax, VA 22030

{ 0 comments }

Some Links

Tyler Cowen warns that Trump is indeed yanking America down the road to socialism. Two slices:

The word socialism is overused in political debate, but during his 10 months in office, Trump has certainly put us on the path toward it. And in case you’re wondering, this is a bad thing: American business has been world-beating for a long time now, in large part because we avoid these sorts of public-private arrangements, which are common in faltering European economies. A dose of government ownership and the associated politicization are not what American industry and innovation need.

There’s a reason we have a private sector to begin with, which is that market realities force companies to efficiently deliver good products at a reasonable price, or else go out of business due to competition.

Now think of everything you know about the federal government and how it operates. Do you observe our own government being successful in cutting costs? Keeping its debt and finances in line? Enforcing standards of accountability? It is laughable to even pose such questions. So given those realities, why should government ownership of private corporations be such a good idea?

To an outsider, the government owning 10 percent of a company might sound like small potatoes. But, typically, a 10-percent share is significant enough and concentrated enough to give that shareholder a large and often decisive voice.

…..

A parting question: What do the Republicans expect will happen the next time the Democratic Party assumes power? Will the Democrats use their equity shares to enforce more DEI? Pass new green energy requirements? Shift contracts toward blue states? Penalize right-leaning CEOs—or push them to shut up?

The rejoinder from the right is that this is how Democrats already behave, and there’s some truth to that. But empowering the government further in these areas is a terrible remedy. That is bound to make things worse, subjecting all sorts of companies to rule by federal fiat. That won’t just be bad for these companies and their ability to compete. It will also prove catastrophic for freedom of speech.

The GOP is traditionally the party that resists this kind of federal overreach into the private sector. Now that it has abandoned that principle, it also has established a precedent for a future left-wing government to take control of America’s most powerful companies. I predict that Republicans will not enjoy the final result.

Also decrying the Trump administration’s increasing socialization of the American economy is Reason‘s Eric Boehm. A slice:

Not even shutting down the government can stop Republicans from forcing their way into corporate boardrooms these days.

The federal government is, at the moment, incapable of completing its most basic and routine task—passing a budget—and yet it is simultaneously expanding its portfolio to include a 10 percent ownership stake in an Alaskan mining company.

Stefan Bartl warns of the “tech-industrial complex.” A slice:

The line between policymaker and producer has all but vanished; the businessman and the bureaucrat are now one and the same. This is no longer a free market but a semiconductor cartel, where government, regulators, and industry titans coordinate the future of computing power. By combining subsidies, ownership stakes, and regulation, Washington leaves little room for genuine competition. This “tech industrial complex” locks in incumbents, crowds out rivals, and turns policy into corporate protection.

Eric Boehm is correct: “Trump’s planned farm bailout should require Congressional approval.”

When government offers trade ‘protection’ on national-security grounds, be aware that every industry under the sun will lobby for such protection. Case in point: U.S. manufacturers of decorative hardwoods assert that they are critical to U.S. national security. (HT Scott Lincicome)

My Mercatus Center colleague Liya Palagashvili rethinks monopsony power in “a multi-earner economy.” A slice:

More Americans are earning income from multiple sources—driving for Uber part-time, running an online business, freelancing, teaching on the side, doing high-level consulting. This isn’t necessarily about people being desperate for extra money (though for some it is). It’s about the fundamental structure of how people earn and think about household income. In the 20th century, it was one job or one career for your whole life. In today’s economy, jobs and careers are more fluid, and up to 60 million Americans are earning income from many different sources.

Of course, the experience varies widely—for some workers, juggling multiple jobs is exhausting necessity, not empowering choice. But for millions of others earning supplemental income by choice, the dynamics are different.

I’m starting to believe that this shift into the multi-earner economy is reducing monopsony power in ways we haven’t fully appreciated yet (not for all workers, but for many).

When you have multiple income streams, you’re simply less dependent on any single employer. If your full-time job cuts your pay or becomes untenable, you already have other revenue coming in—and you already have relationships with other clients or platforms. The cost of walking away drops dramatically.

That’s not theoretical leverage. That sounds more like real bargaining power.

Mark Mix justly criticizes Sen. Josh Hawley’s (R-MO) penchant for carrying water for labor unions. A slice:

The real injustice in union bargaining has nothing to do with the time it takes. The deeper problem is that union contracts apply to every unionized worker, even though many have legitimate reasons to want to reach agreements with their employers directly.

Some workers have enough merit to be paid more than their one-size-fits-all union contract allows. Others may object to the union’s politics or feel the union doesn’t adequately represent them.

Forced unionization harms these independent-minded employees, a problem that passing statewide right-to-work laws outlawing compulsory union payments addresses. Real national labor reform should ensure that union representation and paying union dues are voluntary for every American worker.

Messrs. Hawley and [Sean] O’Brien would prefer to supercharge the coercive status quo. Under the Faster Labor Contracts Act, if a union contract isn’t reached after 90 days of negotiation and 30 days of mediation, an arbitration panel overseen by federal bureaucrats would have the authority to draw up its own agreement and impose it on all parties for two years.

Does anyone think those bureaucrats would do a good job? They’d be required not only to understand a business’s present needs, but also to anticipate future challenges. Putting businesses into a two-year bind crafted by uninformed arbitrators risks destroying companies and leaving employees jobless.

Eager to cozy up to union bosses, Mr. Hawley and other supporters of the bill take their cues from American Compass, a think tank that accepts money from the left-wing Hewlett Foundation given to “move conservative thinking in a more worker-friendly direction.” American Compass brought Mr. O’Brien on a podcast to promote Mr. Hawley’s bill, while Daniel Kishi, an American Compass adviser, praised the bill as “an important step in the right direction.”

Mike Solon ponders the stakes of the government ‘shutdown.’ Two slices:

For Democrats in Washington, the pencils all lack erasers and none of the calculators have a minus button. It’s always addition, never subtraction. The Biden-Schumer-Pelosi spending surge generated the highest inflation in 40 years, the highest interest rates since the subprime crisis, and the loss of the White House, Senate and House. Democrats still insist on no reductions in the post-pandemic spending that fueled their defeat.

Demands to increase healthcare spending are a charade to mask the Democrats’ fury over Republican tax reductions and spending cuts. After the One Big Beautiful Bill Act extended the 2017 tax cut, at a projected cost of $4.5 trillion, and cut spending by $1 trillion, Democratic activists insisted on a futile gesture. Senate Minority Leader Chuck Schumer has obliged, shutting down the government and calling the new law the “Mount Rushmore of fiscally irresponsible bills.”

Have Republicans been excessive in their tax and spending cuts? Hardly. Democrats may point to the Congressional Budget Office’s original budget projections but only by including the CBO’s revisions do the facts become obvious. Spending, not tax cuts, remains the driver of federal debt.

…..

To slow America’s pace on the road to bankruptcy, Republicans must stop Mr. Schumer’s plan. Acquiescing to his shutdown demands would mean not one dime of the post-pandemic’s massive spending surge that generated high inflation and keeps interest rates high is ever recalled.

{ 0 comments }

Quotation of the Day…

… is from page 81 of the late Peter Bauer’s essay “Ecclesiastical Economics: Envy Legitimized,” which is Chapter 5 of Bauer’s superb 1984 book, Reality and Rhetoric: Studies in the Economics of Development:

The notion that the incomes of the more prosperous have somehow been achieved at the expense of the less prosperous has had a long and disastrous history. In its duration and consequences it is perhaps the most pernicious of all economic misconceptions.

DBx: Indeed.

This misconception continues to haunt even modern-day America. From “democratic socialists” such as Bernie Sanders and Zohran Mamdani to “economic nationalists” such as Donald Trump and Oren Cass, the fallacy continues to be spread that the incomes of high-income earners comes largely at the expense of lower-income earners.

{ 0 comments }

Some Links

Scott Lincicome, writing his Capitolism column, makes crystal clear that “Chinese industrial policy is an anchor, not an engine.” Two slices:

Now that the Trump administration has taken an equity stake in domestic mining company Lithium Americas, it’s a safe bet the United States will continue to stray from traditional market capitalism for the foreseeable future. As to why we’re going down this road, the most common answer is—along with Jonah Goldberg’s accurate (IMO) view of the president’s motivations—that this new “American state capitalism” is a response to China’s version of the same. Chinese industrial policies, so the theory goes, have quickly moved the country from an economic nuisance (albeit a large one) to an existential threat, dominating various industries and all but demanding the U.S. government adopt similar policies—subsidies, tariffs, equity infusions, and more—just to keep up. The new Lithium Americas deal follows this script to the letter.

Readers of Capitolism know that, while I agree certain Chinese policies and their effects raise real challenges that demand serious policy responses, the bipartisan approach to countering Chinese state capitalism with American state capitalism is flawed on multiple levels. Most obviously, we’re not China: Policies that might “work” in a still-developing autocracy with 1.4 billion people won’t necessarily “work” here in our smaller, wealthier, messier democracy, and Washington has plenty of untapped alternatives proven to produce desired results at a much lower fiscal, economic, and social cost.

Recently, however, another rather important flaw has emerged: Chinese industrial policies aren’t even “working” over there—maybe even for the industry that’s supposedly their biggest success story.

A big problem with industrial policy—in China, the United States, or anywhere else—isn’t that it never produces a globally competitive “winner” company or industry, but that it will typically produce far more “losers” and do so at a great cost. As we discussed in 2023, research has shown this to be the case in China, too, with failures greatly outnumbering success in key industries like aircraft and semiconductors and accompanied by broader economic harms—resource misallocation, corruption/graft, overcapacity, financial instability, etc.—that “hinder rather than accelerate China’s economic development.”

…..

The obvious counter to these and other hidden costs—including the stuff not produced in China because finite resources were wasted on “zombie” EVs parked in weedy graveyards—is that BYD and a couple other Chinese brands are (so far, at least) leaders in the global EV market and poised to dominate it in the future. Other observers, it should also be noted, are more optimistic about China’s domestic automotive industry in general, seeing any current struggles as a small blemish on a much larger success.

Even so, it would remain the case that EVs are at best an exception to China’s industrial policy rule. As already noted, deep dives into other government-supported sectors—from Branstetter and others—reveal a Chinese government picking many more losers than winners, with supported companies and state-owned champions performing worse than their more market-oriented counterparts in China and still years behind the technological frontier (i.e., where the United States typically is). Just this week, for example, Bloomberg reported that Chinese tech champion Huawei’s most advanced AI chip “can only offer 6% the performance of Nvidia’s next-generation VR200 superchip,” while others doubt Huawei’s products are even as good as Nvidia’s scaled-down “H20″ chip. (One reason why is that Huawei must use Chinese-made chips that are well behind what Nvidia’s products use, thanks to the latter enjoying “a collaborative effort by the whole western community and industry.” Lessons abound!) Even Chinese industries that are globally successful often have problems similar to those facing EVs—or, as this recent Financial Times dive into China’s solar industry documents, even worse issues.

Then there are the broader economic costs arising from China’s state capitalist model—costs that new International Monetary Fund (IMF) research reveals to be mind-bogglingly large. As simply a budgetary matter, the paper estimates that the “equivalent fiscal cost of industrial policy through cash subsidies, tax benefits, subsidized credit, and subsidized land for favored sectors (including both private and state-owned firms)” was annually around 4 percent of China’s GDP between 2010 (when Chinese industrial policy really cranked up) and 2023. Overall, that would mean government spending of around $7 trillion over the period examined—a price tag, the authors note, that could be an understatement due to the other, less-visible government support provided to favored companies.

Steven Koonin reports on yet another case of “climate change bias.” Two slices:

The climate fearful attending Climate Week last month in New York City no doubt shuddered when discussing a recent National Academies of Sciences, Engineering and Medicine report on the effect of greenhouse-gas emissions. Taking a cue from the Brothers Grimm, it depicts dire consequences for the nation’s climate, health and welfare.

The academies’ study—which was put together in less than two months—was obviously meant to bolster the scientific basis for the Environmental Protection Agency’s 2009 finding that greenhouse-gas emissions threaten the nation’s well-being. The study therefore plays down or ignores evidence undermining that conclusion. This agenda is evident from the first sentence of the preface, which invokes the terrible flood of the Guadalupe River in Texas in July. The report doesn’t mention that similar events have been recorded since the late 19th century and show no detectable trend to the present, even as emissions have soared.

Assessments of climate science often minimize, or even ignore, natural variability to make recent climate trends or weather events seem unusual and hence a consequence of greenhouse-gas emissions. The National Academies’ report is no exception. It describes a recent acceleration of global sea-level rise observed by satellites without mentioning a comparable acceleration during the 1930s. There are similar failures in the report’s coverage of U.S. heat waves (which aren’t more common in recent decades than they were in the decades around 1900) and of North Atlantic hurricanes (which show no long-term trends in frequency or intensity).

…..

I helped oversee National Academies studies in engineering and physical sciences for six years. Those reports lived up to the claim to provide “independent, objective analysis and advice.” But the academies have long had problems of bias and advocacy on climate matters. The government would do well to stop funding their climate studies until they get their house in order.

Former “democratic socialists” Joshua Muravchik and Ronald Radosh, writing in the Washington Post, explain – very Hayekianly – that socialism and democracy are fundamentally incompatible with each other. A slice:

What, then, does the DSA stand for? In theory, democratic socialists would transform the economy from private enterprise to public ownership, but — unlike communists — only through persuasion and legislation, not violence and coercion. We each once adhered to this creed.

The problem is that more than a century of history plainly shows that socialism-via-persuasion is a chimera. While democratic electorates may create welfare states and mixed economies, they never opt for full socialism. Just as many other democratic socialists came to understand that they must choose between democracy and socialism, the two of us made peace with democratic capitalism.

Jay Cost explains what shouldn’t – but, alas, what nevertheless today does – need explaining: “By centralizing authority so heavily [in the executive branch], the United States has rejected a fundamental governing principle upon which it was originally founded: the separation of powers.” A slice:

As the French philosopher Montesquieu wrote in The Spirit of the Laws, a work that heavily influenced the Constitution’s framers, combining the executive and legislative means “there is no liberty, because one can fear that the same monarch . . . that makes tyrannical laws will execute them tyrannically.” Likewise, John Adams once noted, “Every project has been found to be no better than committing the lamb to the custody of the wolf, except that one which is called a balance of power.” (Emphasis in original.) As our country’s founders saw clearly, giving the president the right to create and enforce the law is a power highly liable to catastrophic abuse in ways that threaten the foundation of the republic itself.

Moreover, it is only in the legislature that all major factions in society can have their views taken into consideration. The president is just a signal individual who can, at best, reflect but a portion of the country. Those outside the president’s political coalition can do little except bide their time until their side is in control. But a properly functioning legislature is one where a diversity of interests can be brought meaningfully into the policymaking process. That can happen only in Congress. It is the only institution where a variety of views can be expressed, debated, and ultimately integrated into public policy that benefits the whole political community.

Marcus Falcone rightly criticizes governments’ urban planning. A slice:

Remember the joke that getting government help is like having it break your legs and give you a pair of crutches? In this case it’s more like getting both legs broken but getting just one crutch. When it comes to urban planning, the government creates problems and cannot even fix them.

Brian Blase’s and Niklas Kleinworth’s letter in the Wall Street Journal is superb:

The Case for Extending ObamaCare Subsidies” (Letters, Oct. 4) suggests that a Covid-era credit is a lifeline for millions of Americans. Don’t buy it. The sweetened “credit” is the problem, not the solution, driving the high cost of healthcare. The zero-dollar premiums created by the Biden administration policy exacerbated structural problems in the Affordable Care Act.

For everyday Americans, the result is worse coverage and tens of billions in higher taxes annually. Many also have been enrolled in plans without their knowledge, leaving them surprised at tax time or without coverage that meets their needs.

ObamaCare isn’t a healthy insurance market. Only people who receive giant subsidies or expect large medical expenses enroll. For more than one-third of enrollees, taxpayers send insurers large checks for people who never see a doctor, get lab work or fill a prescription. This is twice the amount in a normal market and suggests massive fraud. A recent Paragon policy brief finds that the rise in zero-claim enrollees isn’t, as insurers contend, larger numbers of young, healthy enrollees signing up for plans.

Zero-claim enrollees, many of whom are unaware of their coverage, are part of the problem. There are more than 6.4 million Americans in fully subsidized plans who are ineligible. Unscrupulous brokers filled out applications so people could qualify for zero-premium plans. Meanwhile, insurers happily collected large checks from the government that covered the entire premium. Nearly half of 2025 enrollees took no action during open enrollment, as they were automatically renewed into their subsidized plan.

Unfortunately, Trump administration efforts to address the large-scale fraud have been held up by one Democratic-appointed judge. This makes it more important that the Covid credits expire, and with them, the fuel for the fraud.

ObamaCare’s underlying subsidies would persist without the sweetened deal. The government would still pick up more than 80% of the cost of the premium for the typical enrollee next year after Covid credits expire.

The real beneficiaries of extending the credits are insurers, who would rather receive payments from Washington than offer plans people must at least partially pay for. Hard-working families who get coverage through the workplace shouldn’t have to bail them out to prop up this already oversubsidized market.

{ 0 comments }